Fuzzy Trade Math

As the Doha round of trade talks approaches, the perception that agriculture is the principle issue that will determine success or failure remains accurate. Common assumptions, however, about the magnitude of EU and US subsidies are, in many cases, profoundly inaccurate. The conclusion that the Doha talks are bound to fail because of the obstinacy of developed nations is based on fuzzy math. It does not properly reflect the reality of subsidies, nor the true possibilities for meaningful accord at Doha. The real picture of the magnitude of rich country subsidies emerges when only those subsidies contingent on exports or output are calculated. With this condition applied, the basic level of subsidies does not even approach common, exaggerated claims. In fact, the primary roadblock to agricultural trade comes not from subsidies, but from border barriers, or market access measures. Another misperception is that this is also a rich country problem. The developing world can serve its own interests by compromising here as well. Without confusion around these key issues, the chances for a successful Doha round look much brighter indeed. – YaleGlobal

Fuzzy Trade Math

Arvind Panagariya
Friday, December 2, 2005

Trade talks at Cancun broke down principally because the G-20 group of mainly larger developing countries rejected U.S. and EU offers on reducing their agricultural protection. Two years later, as the Hong Kong Ministerial approaches, agriculture remains the make-or-break issue in the Doha negotiations. But the impasse can be broken once we clear up the misinformation on (a) the magnitude of EU and U.S. subsidies and (b) the level of protection through trade barriers in developed and developing countries in agriculture.

The New York Times has editorialized that the "developed world funnels nearly $1 billion a day in subsidies," which "encourages overproduction" and drives down prices. The World Bank's president, Paul Wolfowitz, similarly referred to developed countries expending "$280 billion on support to agricultural producers" in an op-ed in the Financial Times. Oxfam routinely accuses rich countries of giving more than $300 billion annually in subsidies to agribusiness. Astonishingly, these estimates bear virtually no relationship to the subsidies actually at the heart of the Doha negotiations. Instead, they have their origins in the altogether different measure called the Producer Support Estimate (PSE), published by the OECD. The PSE includes all measures that raise the producer price above the world price, including border measures such as tariffs and quotas. All economists would find the identification of such a measure with subsidies unacceptable.

To measure the true magnitude of subsidies that drive down world prices, we need consider only those subsidies contingent on exports or output. This done, the extent of subsidies turns out to be considerably smaller than $1 billion per day. Thus, rich country export subsidies that have been so much in news have considerably declined in importance in recent years: They currently amount to less than $5 billion, at times as little as $3 billion, annually. Subsidies contingent on output are larger; but they, too, are much smaller than commonly believed: Under the commitments made in the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture, WTO members have achieved substantial reductions in these subsidies. The EU has made a special effort to decouple its domestic subsidies from output as a part of the reform of its Common Agricultural Policy.

Based on the latest data available from the WTO, domestic output subsidies amounted to $44 billion in 2000 in the EU, $21 billion in 2001 in the U.S. and less than $15 billion in 1998 in Japan, Switzerland, Norway and Canada combined. Recognizing that there have been no major cases of backsliding and the EU has made further progress in decoupling its subsidies from output, we can conclude that rich country domestic subsidies that encourage production and lower world prices are substantially below $100 billion.

By focusing exclusively on subsidies, the media has distracted attention from the critical fact that the most important obstacle to agricultural trade comes from border barriers, also called market access measures. And since developing countries are not big offenders on the subsidy front, this focus has promoted the false impression that the agricultural trade barriers are also an exclusively rich country problem. In reality, when it comes to border barriers, developing countries more than match developed countries.

Among the latter, Japan and Europe exhibit high protection while U.S. barriers are relatively low. Thus, in 2001, the trade-weighted average tariff was 36% in Japan, 29% in the European Free Trade Area, 12% in the EU and 3% in the U.S. Of course, these averages mask considerable variation in protection across commodities. Among developing countries, the relatively more protected countries include South Korea with a trade-weighted average tariff of 94% in 2001, India with an average tariff of 44%, China with 39% and Pakistan with 30%. Interestingly, protection even in the developing country members of the Cairns Group, which contains countries with the greatest comparative advantage in agriculture, is not low: In 2001, the average tariff was 13% in Argentina and Brazil, and 11% in Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia.

Once we recognize that export subsidies are minuscule and trade-distorting domestic subsidies much smaller than commonly believed, a successful Doha bargain seems within reach. The elimination of export subsidies and substantial cuts in domestic subsidies do not appear heroic. But if these concessions are to be made the EU and the U.S., they will have to be complemented by reciprocal concessions by others.

The U.S. has a comparative advantage in agriculture, so insists on within-sector reciprocity in the form of market access in return for its concessions on subsidies. The EU and larger developing countries including the Cairns Group, who have high agricultural tariffs, are in a position to offer this reciprocity. But the EU lacks comparative advantage in agriculture. Therefore, it will only be giving concessions in this sector and needs cross-sector reciprocity. Here again the larger developing countries have a crucial role to play. Industrial tariffs remain high in the Cairns Group developing countries as well as in India, China and Pakistan. They can offer the EU the necessary reciprocity.

After all, the Cairns Group in particular will clearly derive large benefits from the rich country reductions in subsidies and tariffs in agriculture and can therefore offer reciprocal concessions in industrial goods and services. Other larger developing countries such as India, China, Pakistan, Indonesia, Korea and Thailand also stand to benefit from increased access to each other's and other developing countries' markets in industrial goods. In addition, they can expect to benefit from the removal of industrial-tariff peaks in the developed countries that apply with potency to labor-intensive products such as apparel and footwear.

Thus, once we cut through the confusion created by constant references to inflated estimates of agricultural subsidies and consider the accurate picture, outlines of a successful negotiation do emerge. Those who consider the barriers to a deal insurmountable need to be reminded that unlike the Uruguay Round, which dealt with win-lose bargains such as those on intellectual-property protection, this round is focused on trade liberalization that largely offers win-win bargains. Both developed and developing countries stand to reap large benefits from the removal of their own subsidies and protection.

Mr. Panagariya is professor of economics and Bhagwati Professor of Indian Political Economy at Columbia.

Copyright © 2005 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved